monchie's flame war

 

monchie's flame war started when he responded positively to the following post:

From: g.spritzer@worldnet.att.net

Subject: Re: How to ensure rent controls.....

Date: 26 Apr 1997 04:14:13 GMT

Organization: AT&T WorldNet Services

 

Cyrus: If rent stabilization is ended or phased out, the

following things will happen:

1) Long-term tenants of rent-stabilized apartments in upscale

neighborhoods with below market rents will see their rents

increase (in some cases significantly).

2) Tenants who live in apartments that are NOT rent stabilized

will see their rents decrease significantly!

3) Tenants who live in poor neighborhoods will see little change

in their rent, since rent stabilized apartments

in these neighborhoods are already at or above market levels.

4) Tenants who live in rent-stabilized studios or one bedrooms

that have "turned over" frequently will see little or no change

in their rents and may even see a decrease! Cyrus, I think you

fall in this category if you are paying over $1400 for a one

bedroom rent stabilized apartment.

 

The tenant activists from the Upper East Side/West Side (who fall

into Category 1 above) have done a good job of convincing the

media that a majority of tenants will see a rent increase if

rent stabilization is phased out. Actually the reverse is true!

Most tenants will see decreases in their rent, since there are

currently about 2 million rental units that are not under rent control

or rent stabilization.

 

and here's monchie's friendly response:

 

From: monchum@interport.net (monchie of nyc)

Subject: Re: How to ensure rent controls.....

Date: Sun, 27 Apr 1997 17:51:23 GMT

Organization: Interport Communications Corp.

 

In article <5jrvel$iqf@mtinsc03.worldnet.att.net>, g.spritzer@worldnet.att.net wrote:

>Cyrus: If rent stabilization is ended or phased out, the

>following things will happen:

>1) Long-term tenants of rent-stabilized apartments in upscale

>neighborhoods with below market rents will see their rents

>increase (in some cases significantly).

 

This will most likely happen, and imo would be a positive development.

 

>2) Tenants who live in apartments that are NOT rent stabilized

>will see their rents decrease significantly!

 

I disagree with this. I suspect that these rents may stay at much the same

rate for several years though.

 

>3) Tenants who live in poor neighborhoods will see little change

>in their rent, since rent stabilized apartments

>in these neighborhoods are already at or above market levels.

 

Very true. And you could also extend this to middle-class areas in the outer

boroughs and upper Manhattan. Here in Inwood in Upper Manhattan, one bedrooms

are currently going for about $700-750 and 2 bedrooms for $850-900, and I

don't see that changing much with decontrol. Again, though, with decontrol,

these rates may not change significantly for several years.

 

>4) Tenants who live in rent-stabilized studios or one bedrooms

> that have "turned over" frequently will see little or no change

>in their rents and may even see a decrease! Cyrus, I think you

>fall in this category if you are paying over $1400 for a one

>bedroom rent stabilized apartment.

 

I agree, and again I think that these rents would probably not rise all that

much for several years.

 

>The tenant activists from the Upper East Side/West Side (who fall

>into Category 1 above) have done a good job of convincing the

>media that a majority of tenants will see a rent increase if

>rent stabilization is phased out. Actually the reverse is true!

>Most tenants will see decreases in their rent, since there are

>currently about 2 million rental units that are not under rent control

>or rent stabilization.

 

I don't think we're going to see decreases if rent controls are abolished, but

I do believe that the higher rates would see very little change. Perhaps there

might be a decrease after several years of decontrol as all the formerly very

cheap, below-market apartments came on the market.

 

Incidentally, with regard to the "activists," I just came across some

interesting figures from the 1990 census about some of the more desirable

Manhattan neighborhoods, courtesy of Street Atlas 4.0:

 

Demographics for ZIP 10024 (roughly the Upper West Side in the 80s)

Median Rent $637

Owner Occupied Housing 24%

Renter Occupied Housing 68%

 

Demographics for ZIP 10023 (roughly the Upper West Side, 60s & 70s)

Median Rent $676

Owner Occupied Housing 25%

Renter Occupied Housing 64%

 

Demographics for ZIP 10014 (West Village)

Median Rent $653

Owner Occupied Housing 17%

Renter Occupied Housing 76%

 

Demographics for ZIP 10011 (Chelsea)

Median Rent $600

Owner Occupied Housing 24%

Renter Occupied Housing 69%

 

The median rents for the East Side were somewhat higher, in the $750-900

range.

 

Remember that median rent means that half of the rents were above this figure

and half were below. That means that in 1990, half of the rents on the Upper

West Side were *******below******** $637/month in 10024 and

**********below********** $676 in 10023 (and of course half were above as

well). This includes all apartments, from studios to 3 bedrooms and up.

 

Now try finding an apartment on the Upper West Side for less than $637 or

$676.

 

What this obviously means is that there are an awful lot of people hanging on

to lower rent apartments in these zip codes, since you can't even touch a

1-bedroom for less than $1200/month.

 

and now here comes monchie's not-so-friendly flamer:

 

From: SteveManes@REMOVEmagpie.com

Subject: Re: How to ensure rent controls.....

Date: Mon, 28 Apr 1997 02:19:49 GMT

Organization: NYC Motorcyclists

 

monchie of nyc (monchum@interport.net) wrote:

: >3) Tenants who live in poor neighborhoods will see little change

: >in their rent, since rent stabilized apartments

: >in these neighborhoods are already at or above market levels.

 

: Very true. And you could also extend this to middle-class areas in the outer

: boroughs and upper Manhattan.

 

It's not true. It may be true in those poor neighborhoods which

_remain_ poor neighborhoods but those which are targeted by gentrification

will see runaway rent increases far beyond the ability of the residents

to pay. Without controls, you would see wholesale evictions of

low-income tenants in borderline neighborhoods, starting in the

East Village and the lowest east side.

 

: Now try finding an apartment on the Upper West Side for less than $637 or

: $676.

 

You can't. $650/mo is exactly what someone earning a NYC median

income of $32k _should_ be paying for rent. It's one-third their

take-home income. What's your point... to throw middle-income wage

earners out of Manhattan?

 

-----------------------[ http://www.magpie.com ]-----------=o&>o---------

Steve Manes | Int'l Bass Players | for info, email

manes@magpie.com | NYC Motorcyclists | server@magpie.com with

94 Harley-Davidson FLHR | Triumph MC Owners | the message text, "lists"

95 Triumph Super III | Motorcycle Safety |

97 Triumph T595 | | N'Yawk, N'Yawk

 

monchie's response to the flame:

 

From: monchum@interport.net (monchie of nyc)

Subject: Re: How to ensure rent controls.....

Date: Mon, 28 Apr 1997 05:20:31 GMT

Organization: Interport Communications Corp.

 

In article <E9Bt52.27G@magpie.com>, SteveManes@REMOVEmagpie.com wrote:

>monchie of nyc (monchum@interport.net) wrote:

>: >3) Tenants who live in poor neighborhoods will see little change

>: >in their rent, since rent stabilized apartments

>: >in these neighborhoods are already at or above market levels.

>

>: Very true. And you could also extend this to middle-class areas in the outer

>: boroughs and upper Manhattan.

>

>It's not true. It may be true in those poor neighborhoods which

>_remain_ poor neighborhoods but those which are targeted by gentrification

>will see runaway rent increases far beyond the ability of the residents

>to pay. Without controls, you would see wholesale evictions of

>low-income tenants in borderline neighborhoods, starting in the

>East Village and the lowest east side.

 

First of all, in that paragraph, I wasn't referring to trendy or

soon-to-be-trendy neighborhoods like the East Village. I was referring

to untrendy (at least for the moment) middle class areas of Brooklyn, Queens,

the Bronx and Upper Manhattan. One of the major attractions of my

neighborhood, Inwood, is that the market rents are relatively affordable for

middle class people. I very much doubt that much would happen other than for

the below-market rents to rise closer to the market level, which is still

affordable by middle class standards. If there is a glut of such apartments

coming on the market, there may also be downward pressure on market prices.

 

As for the East Village, the major reason for the skyrocketing market rents is

a demand for housing in a trendy neighborhood where there is an artificial

shortage. And, IMO, the primary reason for this artificial shortage is the

hoarding of apartments by renters who are paying rents well below market rate.

Heck, if I had a $350/month rent-stabilized apartment in the East Village (or

the West Village, for that matter), I'd do whatever I could to hold onto it.

If I got a job on the West Coast, I'd sublet it for twice or three times that

price, and still know that if I ever got a job back in New York, I'd have a

cheap apartment to come back to. And if I had children, I'd make sure they'd

be able to "inherit" it when I pass away.

 

>: Now try finding an apartment on the Upper West Side for less than $637 or

>: $676.

>

>You can't. $650/mo is exactly what someone earning a NYC median

>income of $32k _should_ be paying for rent. It's one-third their

>take-home income. What's your point... to throw middle-income wage

>earners out of Manhattan?

 

No, I'm trying to make Manhattan more affordable for middle-income wage

earners.

 

Basically, the way rent control/stabilization works now is that people who

have moved in during the last 10-15 years are subsidizing those who moved in

before that.

 

The politicians need the votes of the renters to get elected, but they also

need the money of the landlords in order to run for office. So, over the past

50 years, whenever the landlords have called in their chips with the

politicians, the politicians respond not by allowing big rent increases on the

people who are currently tenants/voters, but by passing the brunt of the

increases onto the people who ****will be***** tenants/voters after the

election -- 1 year after, 2 years after, 10 years after.

 

One typical example of this approach is the grandfathering of rent control in

the early 70s when the switch to rent stabilization took place. The last

figure I saw -- this was about 3 years ago, 20 years after the supposed

switchover to rent stabilization -- was that 10% of tenants were still covered

by rent control, where the rents are based on World War 2 era prices. Another

example is allowing large vacancy increases, which are passed on only to new

tenants, not to people already living in an apartment. My first landlord in

New York City had his own game: He rented primarily to college students from

out of town, knowing that he'd get that vacancy increase every 2-3 years or

so.

 

After 50 years of this system, we have a situation where one tenant may be

paying $350/month for a 3 room apt. simply because they've lived there for 30

years or "inherited" it from their parents, while the person in the exact same

apartment upstairs is paying $1600/month just because they happened to move

into New York City in the 1990s.

 

If controls were removed, the artificial shortage caused by the hoarding of

apartments by renters (and, yes, by landlords as well) would ease, as would

the upward pressure on market rents. When it's no longer rational to hoard an

apartment, people aren't going to do it. And if there is suddenly a glut of

high-priced, formerly below-market-rate apartments on the market, which could

very well happen if controls were removed, then there would be downward

pressure on prices. I predict that if rent controls were removed today, in

5-10 years the market rate for simple 3 room apartments, nothing fancy, on the

Upper West Side would be $700-800 (in 1997 dollars), roughly equivalent to

what the actual median is today. This is a very affordable rent by middle

class standards.

 

By the way, I am not a landlord, nor do I have any relatives who are

landlords. I am a tenant in a rent-stabilized apartment. But I lived part of

my adult life in a big city which did not have rent controls (Philadelphia),

and I can assure you that the housing market is far more rational and

affordable than New York City.

 

 

monchie's flamer's response:

 

From: SteveManes@REMOVEmagpie.com

Subject: Re: How to ensure rent controls.....

Date: Mon, 28 Apr 1997 19:17:48 GMT

Organization: NYC Motorcyclists

 

monchie of nyc (monchum@interport.net) wrote:

: First of all, in that paragraph, I wasn't referring to trendy or

: soon-to-be-trendy neighborhoods like the East Village. I was referring

: to untrendy (at least for the moment) middle class areas of Brooklyn, Queens,

: the Bronx and Upper Manhattan.

 

Ten years ago, everything south of 14th Street and east of 1st

Avenue was decidedly untrendy. Even five years ago, Avenue A was funky

enough to deter gentrification. Today, one-bedrooms on Avenue B can

cost up to $1200. There are two points: one, even with rent controls

the lower east side has been turned on its head with "market value"

speculation and, two, without rent control it will be a green light

to accelerate evictions of families and lower-income residents who

are least capable of paying the doubled and tripled rents which is

exactly what would happen in the East Village.

 

: As for the East Village, the major reason for the skyrocketing market rents is

: a demand for housing in a trendy neighborhood where there is an artificial

: shortage. And, IMO, the primary reason for this artificial shortage is the

: hoarding of apartments by renters who are paying rents well below market rate.

 

That's nonsense. Anyone whose income situation forced them to rent

an apartment in Alphabet City five years ago is almost certainly

not in a financial situation to "hoard apartments". Hoarding

apartments is what speculators have done to scores of buildings on

the LES, waiting for gentrification to push up rents.

 

: Basically, the way rent control/stabilization works now is that people who

: have moved in during the last 10-15 years are subsidizing those who moved in

: before that.

 

What "subsidization" would this be? Landlords are making big money in

this town. If they weren't, we wouldn't be seeing sky-high purchase

prices for rundown buildings in less desirable neighborhoods even outside

Manhattan. The fact is that with stabilization landlords are

earning guaranteed rent increases in excess of CPI and in excess of

support costs, which means not only a guaranteed profit for

landlords but a guaranteed _increase_ in profits every year.

 

: One typical example of this approach is the grandfathering of rent control in

: the early 70s when the switch to rent stabilization took place. The last

: figure I saw -- this was about 3 years ago, 20 years after the supposed

: switchover to rent stabilization -- was that 10% of tenants were still covered

: by rent control, where the rents are based on World War 2 era prices.

 

Actually, as of 1991 it was 6.4%, which means it's probably less than

5% now. This trivial number as a percentage of the whole NYC rental

market is an important one remember when someone invokes an anecdote

about rent _control_ abuse to justify elimination of rent _stabilization_,

which aren't the same.

 

: If controls were removed, the artificial shortage caused by the hoarding of

: apartments by renters (and, yes, by landlords as well) would ease

 

Unfortunately, the facts speak otherwise. Rent controls have been

passed and revoked several times in this century and at NO time did

abolition of controls result in an increase of apartment stock.

 

As for "hoarding", there are plenty of laws already on the books

making it quite easy for landlords to take possession of any

apartment being illegally subletted by a tenant, including

inspection rights and even summonses dragging suspicious tenants

into court to substantiate their primary residence. I know because

this was one of the bullshit legal moves a landlord used against me

to harrass me into leaving my apartment. In my 25 years in NYC, I've

seen several of these illicit sublet arrangements but I've never seen

one of them survive when the landlord made an effort to monitor what

was going on in his building.

 

: I am a tenant in a rent-stabilized apartment. But I lived part of

: my adult life in a big city which did not have rent controls (Philadelphia),

: and I can assure you that the housing market is far more rational and

: affordable than New York City.

 

Suffice to say, Philadelphia isn't and never has been New York City.

 

monchie defends philadelphia's honor:

 

From: monchum@interport.net (monchie of nyc)

Subject: Re: How to ensure rent controls.....

Date: Tue, 29 Apr 1997 05:40:55 GMT

Organization: Interport Communications Corp.

 

In article <E9D49o.GG2@magpie.com>, SteveManes@REMOVEmagpie.com wrote:

>monchie of nyc (monchum@interport.net) wrote:

>: First of all, in that paragraph, I wasn't referring to trendy or

>: soon-to-be-trendy neighborhoods like the East Village. I was referring

>: to untrendy (at least for the moment) middle class areas of Brooklyn,

> Queens,

>: the Bronx and Upper Manhattan.

>

>Ten years ago, everything south of 14th Street and east of 1st

>Avenue was decidedly untrendy. Even five years ago, Avenue A was funky

>enough to deter gentrification. Today, one-bedrooms on Avenue B can

>cost up to $1200. There are two points: one, even with rent controls

>the lower east side has been turned on its head with "market value"

>speculation and, two, without rent control it will be a green light

>to accelerate evictions of families and lower-income residents who

>are least capable of paying the doubled and tripled rents which is

>exactly what would happen in the East Village.

 

Again, you ignore my point: I was referring to the untrendy middle class areas

of Brooklyn, Queens, the Bronx, and Upper Manhattan. And if people are

incapable of paying rents in an area because it's become trendy, they can move

to an untrendy neighborhood where rents are affordable. When I moved to NYC in

1985, I couldn't afford the market-rate rents in the trendy areas -- West

Village, Upper West Side, even the East Village -- so I moved into definitely

untrendy Upper Manhattan.

 

>: As for the East Village, the major reason for the skyrocketing market rents

> is

>: a demand for housing in a trendy neighborhood where there is an artificial

>: shortage. And, IMO, the primary reason for this artificial shortage is the

>: hoarding of apartments by renters who are paying rents well below market

> rate.

>

>That's nonsense. Anyone whose income situation forced them to rent

>an apartment in Alphabet City five years ago is almost certainly

>not in a financial situation to "hoard apartments". Hoarding

>apartments is what speculators have done to scores of buildings on

>the LES, waiting for gentrification to push up rents.

 

Of course landlords have hoarded apartments -- but so have tenants. That's

very obvious from the median rent figures I posted for the Upper West Side and

the West Village. How can the median rents for zip codes 10024, 10023, and

10014 be, respectively, $676, $637, and $653 (1990 census figures) without

massive hoarding by tenants? Those figures mean that in 1990, *****half******

of the apartments on the Upper West Side and the West Village had rents less

than $676, $637, and $653, respectively.

 

Also, according to the 1996 New York City Housing and Vacancy Surveys, the

median contract rent (monthly rent charges, not including utilities) for New

York City as a whole is $593/month. That means that half of all rents in New

York City -- rent-controlled, rent-stabilized, and unregulated -- are below

$593/month. (Source: New York City Rent Guidelines Board Web Page,

http://www.nycrgb.com/Welcome.html)

 

In Alphabet City, I'm sure landlords have hoarded apartments. People don't buy

buildings on the Lower East Side expecting to make money from the rents --

they expect to make money from conversions into luxury buildings, and the best

way to convert them is to keep the apartments empty when tenants move out.

Again, this is another side effect of rent control, since there is potentially

more money to be made with a luxury rental or coop conversion than there is

owning a building with lots of below market rate apartments.

 

>: Basically, the way rent control/stabilization works now is that people who

>: have moved in during the last 10-15 years are subsidizing those who moved in

>: before that.

>

>What "subsidization" would this be? Landlords are making big money in

>this town. If they weren't, we wouldn't be seeing sky-high purchase

>prices for rundown buildings in less desirable neighborhoods even outside

>Manhattan. The fact is that with stabilization landlords are

>earning guaranteed rent increases in excess of CPI and in excess of

>support costs, which means not only a guaranteed profit for

>landlords but a guaranteed _increase_ in profits every year.

 

The subsidization works like this: as I explained, landlords ***have*** gotten

big rent increases over the years, and during the past few years, the

increases have been higher than inflation -- but because politicians are loath

to allow really big increases on current tenant/voters, it's been much more

politically expedient to have ****future**** tenants/voters bear much of the

brunt of the increases. For example, only new tenants have to pay vacancy

increases, which are placed on top of the regular yearly increases; that means

that the new tenant is paying an even heftier increase over the inflation

rate. And if you have a landlord who knows how to achieve a high turnover in

the building (as my former landlord did, by renting primarily to out-of-town

college students), he can get those vacancy increases on a particular

apartment every few years.

 

After 50 years of these kinds of shenanigans by landlords, tenants, and

politicians, you have the very common New York situation where one tenant may

be paying $300/month while the person upstairs with the same exact apartment

is paying $1200/month. Both apartments should probably be renting for

$750/month, but right now the $1200/month tenant is subsidizing the rent of

the $300/month renter.

 

Remember, it does take money to maintain a building, pay taxes, etc., so the

$1200/month renter is paying a much bigger share of those costs than the

$300/month renter, even though both have the same exact apartment.

 

>: One typical example of this approach is the grandfathering of rent control in

>

>: the early 70s when the switch to rent stabilization took place. The last

>: figure I saw -- this was about 3 years ago, 20 years after the supposed

>: switchover to rent stabilization -- was that 10% of tenants were still

> covered

>: by rent control, where the rents are based on World War 2 era prices.

>

>Actually, as of 1991 it was 6.4%, which means it's probably less than

>5% now. This trivial number as a percentage of the whole NYC rental

>market is an important one remember when someone invokes an anecdote

>about rent _control_ abuse to justify elimination of rent _stabilization_,

>which aren't the same.

 

The 10% figure was given to me 3-4 years ago by a tenant activist when I

questioned him about how many people were still living under rent control. I

have not been able to find a current figure on the web.

 

>: If controls were removed, the artificial shortage caused by the hoarding of

>: apartments by renters (and, yes, by landlords as well) would ease

>

>Unfortunately, the facts speak otherwise. Rent controls have been

>passed and revoked several times in this century and at NO time did

>abolition of controls result in an increase of apartment stock.

>

>As for "hoarding", there are plenty of laws already on the books

>making it quite easy for landlords to take possession of any

>apartment being illegally subletted by a tenant, including

>inspection rights and even summonses dragging suspicious tenants

>into court to substantiate their primary residence. I know because

>this was one of the bullshit legal moves a landlord used against me

>to harrass me into leaving my apartment. In my 25 years in NYC, I've

>seen several of these illicit sublet arrangements but I've never seen

>one of them survive when the landlord made an effort to monitor what

>was going on in his building.

 

As far as previous attempts at rent control, I'm only familiar with the

current program, which was conceived in the World War 2 era and then modified

with rent stabilization in the early 70s. If you have some historical

background, I'll be glad to take a look at it.

 

I saw in one of the papers the other day that a landlord claimed that it cost

$5000 to get an illegal tenant evicted. Now, I take that figure with a grain

of salt since it came from a landlord, but I would suspect that it's an

expensive process.

 

>: I am a tenant in a rent-stabilized apartment. But I lived part of

>: my adult life in a big city which did not have rent controls (Philadelphia),

>: and I can assure you that the housing market is far more rational and

>: affordable than New York City.

>

>Suffice to say, Philadelphia isn't and never has been New York City.

 

The biggest difference between New York and Philadelphia is that Philadelphia

has no rent control.

 

For example, let's compare the 1990 median rents for zip codes 19103, 19102,

19107, and 19106 in Center City Philly to neighborhoods which are roughly

equivalent -- the Upper West Side (similar to 19103 and 19102) West Village

(similar to 19107), and Upper East Side (similar to 19106):

 

Demographics for ZIP 19103

Median Rent $575

Owner Occupied Housing 23%

Renter Occupied Housing 65%

 

Demographics for ZIP 19102

Median Rent $641

Owner Occupied Housing 15%

Renter Occupied Housing 67%

 

Demographics for ZIP 19107

Median Rent $475

Owner Occupied Housing 8%

Renter Occupied Housing 79%

 

Demographics for ZIP 19106

Median Rent $762

Owner Occupied Housing 31%

Renter Occupied Housing 54%

 

Now here are the figures for the comparable neigborhoods in New York, Upper

West Side (10024, 10023), West Village (10014), and Upper East Side (10028):

 

Demographics for ZIP 10024

Median Rent $637

Owner Occupied Housing 24%

Renter Occupied Housing 68%

 

Demographics for ZIP 10023

Median Rent $676

Owner Occupied Housing 25%

Renter Occupied Housing 64%

 

Demographics for ZIP 10014

Median Rent $653

Owner Occupied Housing 17%

Renter Occupied Housing 76%

 

Demographics for ZIP 10028

Median Rent $799

Owner Occupied Housing 28%

Renter Occupied Housing 62%

 

What is remarkable here is how similar the median rent figures for comparable

neighborhoods in the two cities are -- and how different the prices are if you

try to go out and rent a new apartment.

 

For example, I could go out tomorrow in Philly's 19103 (1990 median rent $575)

looking for a 3-room apartment for less than $750 and most likely find one in

a few hours. But if I went out in the Upper West Side's 10024 (1990 median

rent $637) for the same exact apartment at the same exact price, agents would

laugh in my face. And the median rent in 19103 is actually $67 ****less****

than in 10024.

 

What this means is that there are an awful lot of below-market-rate apartments

in the New York City zip codes, since, for example, a median rent of $575 in

10024 in 1990 means that half the rents there were ****below**** $575.

 

Yes, Philadelphia is not New York City -- both cities have their pros and

cons. But that is completely irrelevant in this discussion since the median

rents are so similar, yet the rents for a new apartment are so dissimilar. The

difference is, New York's rents have been completely distorted by rent

control, which rewards older tenants at the expense of newer tenants. In

Philly, on the other hand, your rent depends primarily on such factors as

location, view, number of rooms, etc., not on how long you've lived in the

apartment or whether you "inherited" the apartment from your parents.

 

 

monchie's flamer disses philly once more:

 

From: SteveManes@REMOVEmagpie.com

Subject: Re: How to ensure rent controls.....

Date: Tue, 29 Apr 1997 06:50:02 GMT

Organization: NYC Motorcyclists

 

monchie of nyc (monchum@interport.net) wrote:

: Again, you ignore my point: I was referring to the untrendy middle class areas

: of Brooklyn, Queens, the Bronx, and Upper Manhattan.

 

No, you're ignoring my point. With the possible exception of chronically

depressed neighborhoods like Harlem and Bed-Stuy, there's no such thing

as a neighborhood which is immune to gentrification. Even Red Hook is

experiencing trendy feelers.

 

: Also, according to the 1996 New York City Housing and Vacancy Surveys, the

: median contract rent (monthly rent charges, not including utilities) for New

: York City as a whole is $593/month. That means that half of all rents in New

: York City -- rent-controlled, rent-stabilized, and unregulated -- are below

: $593/month. (Source: New York City Rent Guidelines Board Web Page,

: http://www.nycrgb.com/Welcome.html)

 

I accept that, but you're telling only a tiny piece of the full

story. The last _national_ study was in 1993, and it lists the

median average for NYC at $551. Before you sputter and spit again,

that figure is also quite a bit above the national contract rent

average $502. In the 1993 national IAS study, only six US

continental cities had a higher median rent than NYC: San Jose

($810), San Francisco ($709), San Diego ($672), Los Angeles ($647),

Boston ($607) and Seattle ($567).

 

: The subsidization works like this: as I explained, landlords ***have*** gotten

: big rent increases over the years, and during the past few years, the

: increases have been higher than inflation -- but because politicians are loath

: to allow really big increases on current tenant/voters, it's been much more

: politically expedient to have ****future**** tenants/voters bear much of the

: brunt of the increases.

 

That's not "subsidization". That's called "preventing rent gouging".

 

: >Actually, as of 1991 it was 6.4%, which means it's probably less than

: >5% now.

 

: The 10% figure was given to me 3-4 years ago by a tenant activist when I

: questioned him about how many people were still living under rent control. I

: have not been able to find a current figure on the web.

 

See http://tenant.net

 

: As far as previous attempts at rent control, I'm only familiar with the

: current program, which was conceived in the World War 2 era and then modified

: with rent stabilization in the early 70s.

 

Repeating: rent control laws and rent stabilization laws are only

similar in that they are both legislative price controls. That's

where the similarity ends. They are not plug-compatible for the

source of convenient argument. You cannot use anecdotal abuses

under RC to scapegoat RS.

 

: I saw in one of the papers the other day that a landlord claimed that it cost

: $5000 to get an illegal tenant evicted. Now, I take that figure with a grain

: of salt since it came from a landlord, but I would suspect that it's an

: expensive process.

 

It's probably true. It cost me $15,000 to get an illegal tenant

evicted from a property I owned. The property fell into foreclosure

before I was successful. This was in Connecticut, not NYC.

 

: The biggest difference between New York and Philadelphia is that Philadelphia

: has no rent control.

 

Not on your life. Besides a big difference in respective population

sizes, economies, culture and transportation efficiency, the

biggest difference between NYC and Philly is that Philly isn't

historically concentrated on a 24 square-mile island, and developers

target their investment on less than half of it.

 

monchie dissects his flamer's dissing of philly:

 

From: monchum@interport.net (monchie of nyc)

Subject: Re: How to ensure rent controls.....

Date: Tue, 29 Apr 1997 23:42:34 GMT

Organization: Interport Communications Corp.

 

In article <E9E0BF.z6@magpie.com>, SteveManes@REMOVEmagpie.com wrote:

>monchie of nyc (monchum@interport.net) wrote:

>: Again, you ignore my point: I was referring to the untrendy middle class

> areas

>: of Brooklyn, Queens, the Bronx, and Upper Manhattan.

>

>No, you're ignoring my point. With the possible exception of chronically

>depressed neighborhoods like Harlem and Bed-Stuy, there's no such thing

>as a neighborhood which is immune to gentrification. Even Red Hook is

>experiencing trendy feelers.

 

You know, I wouldn't mind living in already gentrified areas like the Upper

West Side or the West Village, and according to the median rent figures, I as

a middle class person should be able to afford it. After all, as I might point

out to a rental agent, the 1990 median rents for 10024 and 10014 were,

respectively, $637 and $653; taking inflation into account, that means that

today the median rents for those zips should be somewhere around $750/month,

perhaps $800 at most. So how come I can't go out today and find an apartment

for $750/month in 10024 or 10014? After all, approximately half of the rental

units in those zips are priced at less than $750/month.

 

Maybe it's because a lot of people are living in below-market rent apartments

that they've had for decades or "inherited" from their parents.

 

>: Also, according to the 1996 New York City Housing and Vacancy Surveys, the

>: median contract rent (monthly rent charges, not including utilities) for New

>: York City as a whole is $593/month. That means that half of all rents in New

>: York City -- rent-controlled, rent-stabilized, and unregulated -- are below

>: $593/month. (Source: New York City Rent Guidelines Board Web Page,

>: http://www.nycrgb.com/Welcome.html)

>

>I accept that, but you're telling only a tiny piece of the full

>story. The last _national_ study was in 1993, and it lists the

>median average for NYC at $551. Before you sputter and spit again,

>that figure is also quite a bit above the national contract rent

>average $502. In the 1993 national IAS study, only six US

>continental cities had a higher median rent than NYC: San Jose

>($810), San Francisco ($709), San Diego ($672), Los Angeles ($647),

>Boston ($607) and Seattle ($567).

 

I believe some of these cities have rent control, though rents are nowhere

near as distorted as they are in New York. The one city I'm slightly familiar

with is San Francisco, since I have some close friends there. My one friend

had a 2-bedroom apartment in a desirable area (The Castro), complete with a

sundeck, and was paying $850/month in 1993. That was the going price for

similar apartments in that area at that time.

 

Now, let's go back to New York, to a similar neighborhood (the West Village),

in 1993. If you went out into the apartment marketplace, could you find a

2-bedroom apartment with a sundeck for $850/month in the West Village in 1993?

No way! You would've had to pay at least $2000/month at that time.

 

So, even though San Francisco had a higher median rent than New York City, the

going rents for apartments seems to be quite a bit lower. Maybe that's because

you don't have the situation where the person in 3A is paying $300/month

simply because they moved in a couple of decades ago or "inherited" the

apartment from his parents, while the person upstairs in 4A, with the same

exact apartment, is paying $1300/month because they had the misfortune of

renting in 1995.

 

>: The subsidization works like this: as I explained, landlords ***have***

> gotten

>: big rent increases over the years, and during the past few years, the

>: increases have been higher than inflation -- but because politicians are

> loath

>: to allow really big increases on current tenant/voters, it's been much more

>: politically expedient to have ****future**** tenants/voters bear much of the

>: brunt of the increases.

>

>That's not "subsidization". That's called "preventing rent gouging".

 

No, it's gouging newer tenants so that people who have lived in their

apartments for decades or "inherited" their apartment from a parent can enjoy

rents that are way below market price.

 

>: As far as previous attempts at rent control, I'm only familiar with the

>: current program, which was conceived in the World War 2 era and then modified

>

>: with rent stabilization in the early 70s.

>

>Repeating: rent control laws and rent stabilization laws are only

>similar in that they are both legislative price controls. That's

>where the similarity ends. They are not plug-compatible for the

>source of convenient argument. You cannot use anecdotal abuses

>under RC to scapegoat RS.

 

They are both still price controls. We do without price controls for food and

clothing, and that system seems to work pretty well. Why not shelter?

 

I want to see a system where landlords are competing for tenants, instead of

the other way around.

 

>: The biggest difference between New York and Philadelphia is that Philadelphia

>

>: has no rent control.

>

>Not on your life. Besides a big difference in respective population

>sizes, economies, culture and transportation efficiency, the

>biggest difference between NYC and Philly is that Philly isn't

>historically concentrated on a 24 square-mile island, and developers

>target their investment on less than half of it.

 

I noticed that you ignored my point that the median rents in comparable

neighborhoods were remarkably similar, yet the apartment marketplaces were so

different. Other differences are inconsequential with regard to their effect

on the apartment marketplace; in fact, both cities are quite similar in many

regards. They are both big Northeastern cities where development has

historically been concentrated in a central area. They both have complex

economies with particular concentrations in the finance sector, advertising,

and other white-collar industries. They both have declining manufacturing

bases. They both have extensive transportation infrastructures and cultural

life.

 

So, how come I can go out and search for a 3-room apartment for $750 or less

in 19102 (1990 median rent $641) and find one in a couple of hours, while in

10024 (1990 median rent $637), such a search would be futile? In these zip

codes, half the rents were under $641 and $637 in 1990, respectively, yet only

in 19102 were such apartments actually available in the marketplace.

 

The only real difference in the apartment marketplaces is that New York has

rent control/stabilization and Philly has no price controls. Philly doesn't

have people living in simple 3-room $200/month apartments in trendy areas, but

it also doesn't have people living in simple 3-room $1500 apartments in trendy

areas either. In Philly, if you're paying $700 for a simple 3-room apartment,

your upstairs neighbor with the same apartment but on a higher floor is paying

maybe $725 at most.

 

I love my adopted city of New York, but I think it would be a much better,

much more affordable place for the overwhelming majority of New Yorkers if

price controls on housing were lifted.

 

 

monchie has a fan - finally:

 

From: ylee@columbia.edu (Yeechang Lee)

Subject: Re: How to ensure rent controls.....

Date: 29 Apr 1997 13:56:13 GMT

Organization: World Domination for Fun and Profit, Inc.

 

monchie of nyc <monchum@interport.net> wrote:

> By the way, I am not a landlord, nor do I have any relatives who are

> landlords. I am a tenant in a rent-stabilized apartment. But I lived part of

> my adult life in a big city which did not have rent controls (Philadelphia),

> and I can assure you that the housing market is far more rational and

> affordable than New York City.

 

Well said. I am as much a Nu Yawk chauvinist and believer in its

innate superiority to the rest of the nation as anyone else, but free

market laws do not suddenly stop working east of the Hudson. How is

it that other big cities like Philly can do without rent control, yet

New York cannot? Why should a former wartime emergency measure be

considered such a sacred cow?

--

http://www.columbia.edu/~ylee/

 

monchie's flamer flames the fan:

 

From: SteveManes@REMOVEmagpie.com

Subject: Re: How to ensure rent controls.....

Date: Tue, 29 Apr 1997 21:04:20 GMT

Organization: NYC Motorcyclists

 

Yeechang Lee (ylee@columbia.edu) wrote:

: How is

: it that other big cities like Philly can do without rent control, yet

: New York cannot?

 

Philadelphia and NYC are two completely different cities. Why is it

that no one wants to live in center-city Los Angeles, but New Yorkers

want to live in Manhattan? Why is it that Philadelphia has some of

the oldest and most decrepit slums in the nation when rent control is

the scapegoat for it in NYC? Cities aren't plug-compatible.

 

: Why should a former wartime emergency measure be

: considered such a sacred cow?

 

Rent CONTROL is a former wartime emergency measure and it was

abolished with vacancy decontrol in the early 70s. Rent

STABILIZATION was born following three years of de-control in the

mid-1970s after the same state legislature which had abandoned

rent CONTROL felt the need to respond to the massive tenant abuses,

gridlocked courts, rent gouging and a potential economic crisis by

passing the Emergency Tenant Protection Act and rent STABILIZATION.

 

monchie thanks his fan:

 

From: monchum@interport.net (monchie of nyc)

Subject: Re: How to ensure rent controls.....

Date: Tue, 29 Apr 1997 23:53:13 GMT

Organization: Interport Communications Corp.

 

In article <slrn5mbvft.ocb.ylee@watsun.cc.columbia.edu>, ylee@columbia.edu (Yeechang Lee) wrote:

>monchie of nyc <monchum@interport.net> wrote:

>> By the way, I am not a landlord, nor do I have any relatives who are

>> landlords. I am a tenant in a rent-stabilized apartment. But I lived part of

>> my adult life in a big city which did not have rent controls (Philadelphia),

>> and I can assure you that the housing market is far more rational and

>> affordable than New York City.

>

>Well said. I am as much a Nu Yawk chauvinist and believer in its

>innate superiority to the rest of the nation as anyone else, but free

>market laws do not suddenly stop working east of the Hudson. How is

>it that other big cities like Philly can do without rent control, yet

>New York cannot? Why should a former wartime emergency measure be

>considered such a sacred cow?

 

Thank you.

 

I consider myself an adopted Nu Yawk chauvinist, but I am constantly amazed by

New Yorkers' myopic inability to see just how crazy the rent control/rent

stabilization system really is. IMO, it's a system which combines the worst

aspects of both socialism and capitalism in one package.

 

- monchie of nyc

 

back to politicsland